Ill',::: ;i!;!,.:;if UBBABIB8 Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium IVIember Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/idiosyncraticproOOange OBWEY 5 5 Technology Department of Economics Working Paper Series Massachusetts Institute of IDIOSYNCRATIC PRODUCTION AND THE RISK, GROWTH, BUSINESS CYCLE George-Marios Angeletos Laurent E. Calvet Working Paper 02-10 February 2002 Room E52-251 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, MA 021 42 This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network Paper Collection at http://papers.ssrn. com/paper.taf?abstract_id=xxxxx loO Massachusetts Institute of Technology Department of Econonnics Working Paper Senes IDIOSYNCRATIC PRODUCTION AND RISK, GROWTH, THE BUSINESS CYCLE George-Marios Angeletos Laurent E. Calvet Working Paper 02-10 February 2002 Room E52-251 50 Mennorial Drive Cambridge, MA 02142 This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network Paper Collection at http://papers.ssrn. com/paper.taf?abstract_id=xxxxx MASSACHUSEHS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY MAR 1 5 2002 LIBRARIES Idiosyncratic Production Risk, Growth, and the Business Cycle George-Marios Angeletos and Laurent E. Calvet* MIT and Harvard University This draft: February 2002 We examine a neoclassical growth economy with markets. Under a CARA-nomial general equilibrium in idiosj'ncratic production risk and incomplete specification for preferences and risk, we characterize the closed form. Uninsurable production shocks introduce a risk premium on private equity, and typically result in a lower steady-state level of capital than under complete markets. In the presence of such risks, rates discourages current risk-taking the anticipation of future low investment and feeds and high interest bcick into low investment in the present. endogenous macroeconomic complementarity thus arises, An which can amplif\' the magnitude and the persistence of the busmess cycle. These results - contrasting sharply with those of Aiyagari (1994) and Krusell risks and Smith (1998) - highlight that can have significant adverse effects idiosyncratic production or entrepreneurial on capital accumulation and aggregate volatility. Keywords: Entrepreneurial Risk, Investment, Growth, Fluctuations, Precautionary Savings. JEL Classification: D5, D9, E2, E3, 01. 'Correspondence: 50 Memorial Drive, Cambridge, MA 02138, laurent_calvet@harvard.edu. MA This manuscript 02142, angelet@mit.edu; Littauer Center, Cambridge, is a thoroughly revised version of an earlier working paper, "Incomplete Markets, Growth, and the Business Cycle". Robert Barro and John Campbell from D. Acemoglu, P. for detailed Aghion, A. Alesina, J. We are especially grateful to Abhijit Banerjee, feedback and extensive discussions. Benhabib, A. Bisin, R. Caballero, We also received helpful F. Caselli, C. Foote, comments O. Galor, J. Geanakoplos, M. Gertler, J.M. Grandmont, O. Hart, N. Kiyotaki, D. Laibson, N.G. Mankiw, M. Mobius, G. Moscarini, H. Polemarchakis, M. Schwarz, K. Shell, R. ShiUer, C. Sims, R. Townsend, T. Vuolteenaho, and seminar participants MIT, NYU, Yale, Summer Macro Workshop. at Brown, Harvard, Maryland, 2001 Minnesota the 2000 Conference of the Society of Economic Dynamics, and the Introduction 1 The standard model neoclassical growth Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans assumes complete markets, of implying that private agents can fully diversify idiosyncratic risks in their production and invest- ment However, large undiversifiable entrepreneurial and production activities. paramount risks are not only developed countries, but also cjuantitatively significant even in the most ad- in less vanced economies. In a recent study of document that entrepreneurs extreme dispersion US private equity, Moskowitz and Vissing-j0rgensen (2001) face a "dramatic lack of diversification" in their investments in their returns.^ Similarly, moral hazard and an and agency problems imply that the executives of publicly traded firms are very exposed to the risk in the production and investment decisions they make on accumulation of A human natural question behalf of the shareholders. Large idiosyncratic risks are also evident in the or intangible capital. is then how the presence of large undiversifiable idiosyncratic risks in en- trepreneurial, production, and investment choices, matters for paper we propose that incomplete macroeconomic outcomes. risk sharing leads to substantial underaccumulation of capital and generates a powerful amplification and propagation mechanism over the business We The technology is standard neoclassical and and each agent can invest as to idiosyncratic uncertainty. much If both a consumer and a producer. convex. There are no credit-market imperfections as he likes in his production. However, production and the model wo\ild reduce to a standard is subject fully diversify Ramsey economy. markets are incomplete, however, individuals must bear at least part of the idiosyncratic risk in their production and investment choices. Our model belongs tlie to the class of general-eqmlibrium economies with incomplete markets United States, private companies accounted Moskowitz and Vissing-Jorgensen for fully is markets were complete, indi\'iduals would be able to their idiosyncratic production risks, '111 cycle. introduce idiosyncratic production risk and incomplete insurance in an otherwise standard neoclassical growth economy. In our model, each private agent When In this whom also observe that for about half of production and corporate equity "About 77 percent of all private equity is and in 1998. owned by households private equity constitutes at least half of their total net worth. Furthermore, households with private equity ownership invest on average more than 70 percent of their private holding in a single private company, household has an active management interest. [...] in which the Survival rates of private firms are around 34 percent over the first 10 years of the firm's hfe. Furthermore, even conditional on survival, entrepreneurial investment appears extremely risk)', generating a wide distribution of returns." "Castenada et al. (1998) and Quadrini (2000) have argued that entrepreneurship is wealth distribution- Heaton and Lucas (2000) have shown that entrepreneurial income to explain portfohos and risk premia. important is in explaining the also important empirically Models of heterogeneous infinitely-lived agents. from the "curse of this class typically suffer mensionality" because the wealth distribution - an infinite-dimensional object variable. By considering exponential preferences and Gaussian risks, gates independent from the wealth distribution. is we render di- a relevant state the macro aggre- The equilibrium dynamics are then characterized in closed form. The analytical tractability of the model allows us to clearly identify how uninsurable idiosyn- both individual choices and aggregate outcomes. Because exposure to cratic production risk affects production risk can be controlled through the level of investment, production risk has an ambiguous impact on precautionary savings. Most importantly, production risk introduces a private equity and therefore unambiguously reduces the aggregate sult, demand for risk premium on investment.'' As a re- the steady-state levels of capital and income typically decrease with the variance of uninsurable production shocks. Perhaps more surprisingly, idiosyncratic production risks introduce a kind of endogenous dy- namic macTveconomic complementarity, which can slow down convergence to the steady state, amplify exogenous aggregate shocks, and increase the persistence of the business cycle. This macroeconomic complementarity has a simple origin. When uncertainty, an individual's willingness to invest depends on is subject to idiosyncratic his ability to self-insure against un- Risk premia and investment diversifiable shocks to future production. anticipated future credit conditions. production In our model, high interest rates demand thus depend on and low investment in period feed back into high risk premia, low risk-taking and low investment in earlier periods. one Low investment, low income, and low savings can thus be self-sustaining for long periods of time. The basis of this mechanism is a particular pecuniary externality. If agents save too httle in one period, they discourage risk-taking and investment This externality arises only complementarity is in the presence of idiosyncratic periods via the interest rate. production risks. The macroeconomic thus a genuine general-equilibrium implication of a market imperfection. The macroeconomic complementarity ing constraints. in earlier Our mechanism is arises in our model even though agents face no borrow- thus independent from - and is in fact complementary to - the amplification and propagation mechanisms that are generated by credit-market imperfections.^ Important examples include Aiyagari (1994, 1995), Constantinides and Duffie (1996), Heaton and Lucas (1996), Huggett (1993, 1997), Krusell and Smith (1998), and Rios-RuU (1996). See Rios-RuU (1995) and Ljungqvist and Scirgent (2001) for a review of this Hterature. ' Our model thus complements earlier research, which has stressed the impact of aggregate production shocks on investment. See for instance Acemoglu and Zilibotti (1997) for the complete market case. ^See for instance Bernanke and Gertler (1989, 1990), Kiyotaki and Piketty (1999). Moore (1997), and Aghion, Banerjee and We share with this hterature the idea that market imperfections can have important imphcations we First, modeh however, outcomes. Our for aggregate differs from these earher approaches in three ways. focus on incomplete insurance, which affects the willingness to invest, rather than borrow- ing constraints, which also affect the ability to invest. (OLG) rather than overlapping generations on finite-horizon effects Second, we consider infinitely-lived agents economies; this ensures that our results do not depend and makes our framework directly comparable to the standard RBC frame- work. Third, the pertinent literature has centered around the dependence of aggregate outcomes on the wealth distribution as the only channel through which market incompleteness can generate propagation and amplification; the pecuniary externality identified in this paper has not been considered before and it is thus an innovative finding on its own that incomplete markets can generate amplification and propagation even in the absence of the wealth-distribution channel. Our analysis concludes that incomplete insurance generates untfeT-investment in the steady state and increases both the magnitude and the persistence of aggregate fluctuations. Aiyagari (1994) and Krusell and Smith (1998) also examined the effect of incomplete markets in the neoclassical growth model, but reached a dramatically different conclusion. They argued that incomplete insurance generates overinvestment in the steady state and has no important effect on the business cycle. The contrast between their results and ours has a simple origin. production uncertainty as the main source of consider instead the effect of idiosyncratic individual investment. Idiosyncratic do not introduce a in risk taking. This explains and business-cycle The risk premium on rest of the effects paper why Aiyagari (1994) and Krusell and Smith (1998) endowment shocks, which do not endowment shocks affect the returns on influence only precautionary savings. They private equity and thus do not generate a pecuniary externality Aiyagari and Krusell and Smith did not identify the steady-state documented is risk, While we view idiosyncratic in this paper. organized as follows. Section 2 introduces the economy and Section 3 analyzes the individual decision problem. In Section 4 we characterize the general equilibrium in closed form, analyze the steady state, and describe the propagation and amplification mechanism that arises in the presence of idiosyncratic production risk. simulations. We and directions 2 Section 5 presents some numerical conclude in Section 6 with some remarks on the Ukely robustness of our findings for future research. All proofs are in the A Ramsey Economy Appendix. with Incomplete Risk Sharing This section introduces a neoclassical growth economy with decentrahzed production, erences, Gaussian idiosyncratic uncertainty, and an exogenous incomplete asset span. CARA pref- Technology and Idiosyncratic Risks 2.1 Time is discrete and infinite, indexed by t N= G variables are defined on a probability space They are all born at date Eacli individual using his own 0, live forever, ( , A:/ and satisfies the investment. The Tlie economy is The technology and single who is endowment f{k) = The output F is deterministic and The F{k,l).' individual controls same labor supply, through his J}.*^ in every date. own production scheme operates his standard neoclassical. con- It exhibits labor, decreasing returns with respect to the of his production in period l^ total factor productivity fc^ random G J ={1, •, We individual can invest in a single type of capital. t. individuals have the all j all Inada conditions. There are no adjustment costs and no in period The production function by consumption good the stock of capital that individual j holds at the beginning of period labor and stocliastic P). Individuals are indexed , and consume a stant returns to scale with respect to capital divisibilities in T ...}, also a producer, or entrepreneur, is labor and capital stock. capital/labor ratio, {0, 1, common — Aj across all t, is t and by l\ in- denote by his effective given by AlF{kl,lf). We individuals. assume that and thus conveniently consider the function I, a random shock specific to individual is investment at date t-1, while A^ is Production and returns are thus subject to idiosyncratic uncertainty. The j. observed only at date This risk is what we t. call idiosyncratic production risk (or, technological, entrepreneurial, or investment risk, depending on our preferable interpretation). For comparison with production e^ introduce endowment risks, it is useful to also We risks. let denote the exogenous stochastic endowment of consumable good that individual j receives in period t. These shocks model and do not risks that are outside the control of individuals production or investment opportunities. The overall non-financial income of individual j in affect period t is yi The random shock A^ is = Aif{ki) + endowment multiplicative, while the (1) ei. risk e^ is additive. Asset Structure 2.2 Idiosyncratic risks can be partially hedged by trading a limited set of short-lived securities, which are indexed amount The of by m e {0, l,..,Af}. Purchasing one unit of security consumption dm,t+i at date vectors The model ttj = iTTm,t)m=o ^^"^ '^ — t + l. The > > f"{k) Vfe G at date price of this security at date i^,t)m=o directly extends to economies with a '/ satisfies f'{k) m ^i'^' continuum (0,oo), Umfc„o/'(fc) = t t is yields a denoted by respectively, the price vector of agents. oo, and lmik-.oof'{k) = 0. random TTm.t- and the payoff vector at date t. = 1 delivers dot gross that t and Rt = and t + assets m and 1/ttoj M} e {1 ?( = Default At the outset contemporaneous realization of is The bond Rt-l denote respectively the is rule out Finally, for simplicity, of every period asset payoffs, dt, We not allowed. any other kind of credit-market imperfections. {(yl(,ej)}jgj. Information are risky. 1. assets are in zero net supply.* all are informed of the t, individuals and idiosyncratic shocks, thus homogenous^ across agents and generates a filtration {!Ft}tZo- denote by Et the expectation operator conditional on Tt. Preferences 2.3 To t, and exogenous and generally incomplete. is short-sales constraints or We a riskless bond, between interest rate asset span we assume is with certainty in every and the net The m= Security distinguish between intertemporal substitution and risk aversion, we adopt a preference cation that belongs to the Epstein-Zin non-expected utility class. Consider utilities U A and T. specifi- two concave Bernoulli stochastic consumption stream {c(}^o generates a stochastic utility stream {ut}^o defined by the recursion Uiut) where CEt{u) = = Uict) pU[CEt{ut+i)] Vf > + T"-'[EtT(u)] denotes the certainty equii-alence of u. governs risk aversion, while the cur\-ature of U measured = T thus When T = [/, The curvature of Eq ^J^q/3'{/(c(). Finally, note that consumption units. in CARA-Normal 2.4 (2) governs intertemporal substitution. these preferences reduce to standard expected utility, U{uo) Ut is directly 0, Specification Closed-form certainty-equivalent measures are not possible for general risks and general preferences, but can be obtained Assumption 1 in CARA-normal the (Exponential Preferences) Agents have U{c) Ricardian equivalence holds ' debt is financed by case. lump-sum in = -* expC-c/*). T(c) =. identical recursive utility (2) with -(1/r) exp(-rc). (3) our model because there are no credit-market imperfections. As long as public ta.xation, there is thus no loss of generality in assuming that the riskless bond is in zero net supply. The results of this paper would not be modifed under the alternative assumption that income shocks are privately observed, provided that the structure of the economy remains common knowledge. Assumption 2 (Gaussian Risks) The idiosyncratic risks {(>!(, e^)}jgj and asset returns dt are jointly normal. Note that a high ^ corresponds to a strong willingness to substitute consumption through time, while a high T implies a high risk aversion. for analytical tractability, paper. They can also The above two but do not appear to be restrictions are critical for motivated by the desire any of the main arguments in this be viewed as a kind of approximation to an economy with more general preferences and risk distributions. CARA-normal economy to Section 5 will propose a cahbration match a constant method that permits our and a constant elasticity of intertemporal substitution degree of relative risk aversion at the steady state. We make two additional assumptions. Assumption 3 (No Persistence) The residuals of the projection of {(Aj, e^)}jeJi on the span of dt are serially uncorrelated This will imply that an individual's saving and investment choices are independent of his con- temporaneous idiosyncratic income and productivity shocks, a property that aggregation but analysis, we will is certainly not important for any of our qualitative results. mimic persistence with a long time Assumption 4 (No Aggregate Uncertainty) and ^^ei/J=E(_ie^' = In for our quantitative interval (see Section 5). all dates and events, ^jAl/.J — E(_i^j = A 0.10 This restriction, too, only serves the tractability of the model; all As will greatly simplify macro variables are deterministic in equilibrium. We it will will discuss, imply that asset prices and however, the implications of our results for an economy with aggregate uncertainty. 3 Decision Theory This section examines the decision problem of an entrepreneur. We show that the portfolio choice reduces to a mean-variance problem, and derive the optimal saving and investment rules. This assumption follows naturally from the agents facing independent shocks. Law of Large Numbers when the economy contains an infinity of The 3.1 Individual's Consider an individual by his non-financial i\, (^mf)m=o- -H^^ j in Problem period t. income by budget constraint Denote y^ and , Iris consumption by is y[ is given by (1). in dfe{, Capital accumulates according to e{ then restate the budget constraint A:j_,_j we satisfies the budget constraint where i\, 6 G [0,1] conveniently rewrite the decision ^f6{=4- K+i + (5), We (5) = {c[, k^^^, ^t' max *^^* maximizes Uic',) . Bellman equation, +0U (cE,[V,^i«i)l) and the transversality condition hmt_oo/?'Et[/[V'/(w^)] sponding optimal consumption rule by Wlf^o (5). indirect utility of wealth V/ (w) satisfies the U[V/{u,i)] = (6) , 0. We denote the corre- c^(ty)- Consumption-Investment Decision 3.2 CARA sets + {l-6)k^ inclusive of the capital stock. i. Given a price sequence {ttjJ^q, agent j chooses an adapted plan subject to = (4) as 4+ and (4) + dfe\ represents the agent's total wealth (or cash-in-hand) at date The — terms of stock variables. The quantity y,l=AU{kl)+{l-8)l4 + utility risky assets by 0^ is the fixed depreciation rate of capital. To simplify notation, problem pliysical-capital in\-estment bond and the his portfolio of the i+il+TTfe[=yl + where c^. iris preferences, coupled with no short-sales constraints, imply that the and productive distribution, which capital are is of course stochastic, together with Assumption we present independent of wealth. 4, will ensure that in this section the decision the interest rate is wiU not all We affect the macro theory when the demand can thus anticipate that the wealth aggregate dynamics. This property, variables are deterministic. For this reason, risk premium on financial assets "See Angeletos and Calvet premium on is zero and deterministic.^^ (2000) for the general analysis. There, we first characterize individual choices for arbitrary asset prices and then prove that there exists an equiUbrivun such that the interest rate the risk for risky as- all assets me {1, ...,M} is zero. is deterministic and An educated guess consumption is equihbrium price path, the value that, along the where al,al > and M and ^,6( € 4{w) = aiw + bl non-random are where Tl = t+ 1. Without payoffs. be determined. coefficients to We VtUwU,] = K. Ei<i-f^Vari«j)/2l measures absolute risk aversion in period raj_,_j We then infer from (8) , with respect to wealth variation in t henceforth call Fj the effective degree of absolute risk aversion at date we normalize loss of generality, Since there hedging purposes. is project .Aj^j and 1) to t. have zero expected no risk premium, the assets have zero prices and are thus only used For any ej_,_2 (m > risky securities all (c^,A;^ the optimal portfolio (^mt)m=i j,6'qj), ^^ for therefore chosen to This has a simple geometric interpretation. minimize the conditional variance of wealth. We on the asset span: M+i = The (7) (7) that CEt period and the optimal rule are linear in wealth: V,'{w)=aiw+V,, (3) iiuiction dt+i i^i+i projections k^^j c^+i and ^^ j + 4+1 4+1^ = + 4+v dt+i ^l+i (^t+i represent the diversifiable components of the idiosyncratic The residuals production and endowment shocks. and t7(_,_j Only the oi df+i, correspond to the undiversifiable components. which are orthogonal to the span e^+j, latter matter for either individual choices or aggregate outcomes. Their variances, The are thus useful measures of financial incompleteness.^'^ corresponds to a^ = and a^ = 0. The incomplete-market economies and Krusell and Smitli (1998) correspond to but no idiosyncratic production/investment (production/investment fXg > but risks). Vart(ui^_^j) '"The implicit assumption that relaxed. Besides, A and <Te case (additive idiosyncratic income risks we are most interested is when a a > — (j^ + w^_,_i = /(^+i)'^cr^. (A-l-77^+i)/(A:^)-l-(l-(5)fcj -|-£^_,_j-f ^q It is convenient to define $(fc) j = {l-6)k as the expected production function; and Gik, (J = considered by Aiyagari (1994) risks). and has conditional variance + it_4 The After optimal hedging, individual wealth reduces to Af{k) case of complete Arrow-Debreu markets if we wanted tjJ^j and f = ^k)-f ) t\j^\ Eire [al + jikfa"^ stationary, so that /2 g a and a e are independent of to captiire the fact that idiosyncratic risk worsens during recessions, be functions of aggregate wealth. t, can be easily we could also let as the nsk-adjusted output. By (8), (r^,fc^_^j. 0q thus maximizes + pu{v]i, [G(ki^„fi) + u{cl) subject to the budget constraint, j) c^ + fc^_|_j + 0^ JRt = eQ} urj Under complete markets, the optimal investment equates the marginal product of the interest rate: Rt = ^'{kt+\). return on investment is discounted for capital with In the presence of uninsurable production risks, however, the risk. The FOCs with respect to and ^q k^ imply the key , condition for investment demand: Rt The = ^{kU,St) = ^'(fc^+i)-r^/(A-/+i)/'(^i+i)ai agent equates the nsk-adjusted return with the risk-free rate. pected marginal product of capital and the risk-free rate, on private equity. This premium is The $'(A-j_^j )-/?;, (9) difference between the ex- represents the risk premium proportional to the uninsurable production risk (t^ and the effective risk aversion Tt- The FOC with respect to the riskless rate implies the Euler equation, Etci^,-c> =<i>HpRt) + rVar,(c;^i)/2. (10) Expected consumption growth thus increases with the variance of consumption. This reflects the standard precautionary motive for savings (Leland, 1968; Sandmo, 1970; Caballero, 1990; Kimball, 1990). The sensitivity of sa\dngs to sensitivity to the interest rate The consumption rule is to a{. The risk is governed by risk aversion (F), while their governed by intertemporal substitution (^). and the budget constraint imply that future consumption in current wealth wj, with slope must be equal consumption MFC {dc[j^_-^l dw\j^-^){dwlj^-^l dw^) — a\_^-^Rt{l-a\) therefore satisfies the recursion al = 1/[1 -I- . By c^_,.j is linear (10), this slope {a^^^^RtY^]. Iterating forward yields The MFC is thus the inverse of the price of a perpetuity, which delivers one unit of the consumption good in each period s > t. Finally, the envelope condition -after simple F( = Fa^^_j. We 1 'a\ thus infer from (11) that the effective absolute risk aversion F( function of future interest rates. Proposition manipulation- implies that We summarize our results = is a\ and thus an increasing below (Individual Choice) For any path {/^jJ^q, the value function and the consump- tion rule are linear in wealth, as in (7), and the 10 coefficients al and 2^ are equal and satisfy (11). The demand investment for i?i Consumption and savings = is given by + il-6)-fif{ki^,)f{ki^,)aX Af'iki^,) (12) are characterized by the Euler ecjuation, ' Et4+,-4=^\ni0Rt) + ^VaTt{4+,), where Varf(c^_^i) aversion Fj = = 3.3 is {al_^_^)'^[al + /(A:^+i)V^]. Finally, the efFective risk interest rates increase the effective risk aversion Fj private investment. current risk-taking = increases with future interest rates. raj_,.j Note that higher future premium on (aj_^j)^Var((u;j^j) (13) much more We and thus the risk expect than the feedback from future credit conditions to general than our model, as will be discussed in Section 4.3. Comparative Statics Consider the impact of incomplete markets on investment. The optimality condition (12) defines the optimal investment as a function of the contemporaneous interest rate, the effective risk aversion, and the production risk: and the production risk a^^, optimal investment k^_^_^ fc(_,_j = but A;(i?f,cr^, Ff). is This function decreases with the interest rate Rt independent from the endowment risk a^. Wlien a a also decreases with the effective risk aversion F^. aversion increases with future interest rates. By > 0, the (11), effective risk Incomplete markets therefore introduce a negative feedback from future interest rates to current investment demand. Proposition 2 (Investment) Investment demand decreases with idiosyncratic production 9A;j_,_j/5fT4 dk^j^-y/dRs < < 0. When a^ > Vs > i. 0. higher future interest rates reduce investment Moreover, production with respect to their impact on investment: Under incomplete markets, in future periods. means that A risk 9^fc^ and future , interest rates are j/(5a"^5i?s) < Vs > risk-taking in one period depends on the ability to risk: demand: complementary t. smooth consumption higher borrowing rate, or a more stringent credit market, in any given period self-insurance is more difficult in the period. This in turn raises risk premia and discour- ages investment in earlier periods. In Section 4.3, we will demonstrate that this feedback generates a kind of dynamic macroeconomic complementarity, which can be the source of amplification and persistence over the business cycle. 11 Proposition 2 also states that a high level of production risk and a high level of future interest rates reinforce each other's impact ment invest- we document in this and bad credit conditions, the amplification and persistence risks paper are on investment. Because recessions tend to predict high likely to effects be particularly important during recessions. Consider next the impact of incomplete markets on savings. Although the effect of an increase in endowment risk is income (13), when (7,4 positive, the effect of production is endogenous. It is risk /(^t+i)^cryi actually decreases despite indeed much increases too much, the individual scales back investment kj^^ so that the increase in a a- From the Euler equation we conclude: Proposition 3 (Savings) An increase and consumption growth, aA is (^A a— in endowment (E(C^^j-C(). generally ambiguous. capital share 1/2, there On erg, raises both wealth risk, Vart(W(_,_j), the other hand, the impact of the production risk For example, is risk, a threshold in the case of ct>i such that a Cobb-Douglas technology with dV art{w^_^^) / da a < if and only if >'^A- While the literature has focused observe that this channel effect unambiguously is small or even ambiguous, because exposure to production risk possible that, his on precautionary savings risk is on the effect of incomplete markets on precautionary savings, we ambiguous in the presence of production risks. In contrast, the direct on private investment unambiguously reduces investment, and seems hkely to dominate in equilibrium. 4 General Equilibrium and Steady State In this Section we characterize the general equilibrium and the steady state of the economy in closed form. 4.1 Definitions Recall that there CARA-normal is no exogenous aggregate uncertainty (Assumption specification, the wealth distribution which prices are deterministic. these assets in equilibrium. of the uninsurable If is irrelevant. We and that, because of our thus focus on equilibria in asset prices are deterministic, there can be FUsky assets thus play only one role in component 4) of idiosyncratic production 12 no risk premium on the model - the definition and endowment risks. Furthermore by Assumptions out in the aggregate and are normally distributed: 2-4, undiversifiable risks cancel ,40 cj^ and are thus sufficient statistics for the structure of risks and the (Tg terized by = £ incomplete- markets equilibrium lection of stoie-conim^ent plans ({c^, maximizes the tion, what 4.2 We follows, we let C(, fc^_|_i, each agent utility of Wt and Kt+i wealth and capital. The for the economy can be parame- {(3,r,'ii,F,A,6,aA,cre)- An Definition In Vj,i. initial is a deterministic price sequence {ttjI^q ^j, u't }t^o)i6J and j; asset such that: markets clear and a col- t«^}^ The plan {c^, in every date and event, A;j_j.j, O^, respectively denote the population averages of consump- mean wealth, Wq = Y1,j=\^qI J^ '^ ^^^ exogenous parameter economy. Equilibrium Characterization first observe that (11) implies that aversion a\ — (12). First, because preferences exhibit investment (A:j_,_j) and T\ at is = Tat for all all j, f. agents share the same We and the same effective risk next observe two important properties of condition CARA and there are no borrowing constraints, the optimal independent of contemporaneous wealth [wl). This ensures that the wealth distribution does not matter for equilibrium allocations. investment risk MPC (cr^), and Second, because technology (/, 6,^4), effective risk aversion {Tat+i) are identical across agents, all agents choose the same level of investment k^j^-^ = Kt + \ for all j,t. Aggregation is thus straightforward and we conclude: Theorem 1 (General Equilibrium) There the macro path {Ct, ^t+i, H^t, i?j}J^Q is exists an incomplete-markets equilibrium in deterministic and productive investment. The equilibrium path Rt Ct+i-Ct = all satisfies in all i agents choose identical levels of > ^'{Kt+iyrat+if{Kt+i)f'{Kt+i)(j\ = * Hl3Rt) + Ta^+, [ol + f{Kt+ifa\] ««=[!+ ES(^*-R*+i--^t+s)"T' Ct + Kt+i Wt+i = which . (14) /2, (15) (16) Wt, (17) = HKt+i). (18) 13 Conditions (14) and (16) follow directly from the individual decision problem. Equation (15) tained by aggregating the individual Euler equations. production risks, (14) markets Euler equation, U'{Ct) constraint and the production = endowment ob- there were no undiversifiable idiosyncratic If = would reduce to the familiar complete-markets condition Rt in addition there were no undiversifiable is risks, ^'{Kf+i). If then (15) would reduce to the complete- PRtU'(Ct+i)- Finally, conditions (17) and (18) are the resource economy, which of course remain the same under frontier of the either complete or incomplete markets. Under incomplete markets, the aggregate consumption growth increases with the variance down individual consumption. This reflects the standard precautionary motive and will push of the equilibrium risk-free rate. More interestingly, the presence of uninsurable idios5Ticratic production risks introduces a risk premium on given risk-free rate. This risk premium and represents a gap between the We {pi) in finally note period rates raises the risk equal to is social R^ premium on In the next subsection, = p, down aggregate investment ^'{Kt+i)~Rt = {Tat+i) f {Kt + i) for all s > f. risk aversion (Tat+i) That is, and thus the an anticipated increase private equity and thereby decreases the we show that for any f {K t+i)cr'^^ and the private return to investment. from (11) that the effective increase with t private equity, which pushes this feedback generates a risk premium in future interest demand for investment. kind of dynamic macro economic complementarity, which induces persistence and amplification in the transitional dynamics. Propagation and Amplification: 4.3 An Endogenous Dynamic Macroeconomic Complementarity Consider an economy which, starting from the steady state, pated negative wealth shock. is quite familiar. The impact is hit at a given date of such a shock in a complete -markets Consumption and investment fall, interest rates rise, t by an unantici- Ramsey economy and the economy converges monotonically and asymptotically back to the steady state. The transition is slow under complete markets only because agents seek to smooth consumption through time. But, when markets are incomplete, the intertemporal substitution effect is complemented by a risk-taking effect. Anticipat- ing high interest rates in the near future, private agents are less willing to invest in risky production. This as effect amplifies the fall in initial compared investment and slows down convergence to the steady state to complete markets. Below, we illustrate this mechanism in a simplified version of the model. Example. To Suppose that markets are incomplete clarify the presentation, we denote by It = in period but complete at i Kt+i the gross investment chosen by 14 G {l,..,oo}. all investors in period Given wealth t. VK], we can solve for the = C*{Wi) Fq = Fai, is Ramsey > equilibrium at dates t = By and write 1, period-1 consumption as Ci and period-1 investment as risk aversion in an increasing function of future interest rates, {Rt}'^i- In any period period > t 0, the interest rate 1, Since investment at t > 7] I*{Wi). (11), effective — equal to the marginal productivity of capital, Rt is 2 increases with Ii, interest rates at all i > 1 decrease with h. $'(/{). We can therefore express the period-0 effective risk aversion as a function of period-1 investment alone, To = We r*(/i).^'' note that the functions C* and /* are increasing while T* decreases in wealth, with investment. We suppose for expositional simplicity that zero in every period t ^ Wealth 1. period in the aggregate endowment 1 is Wi = $(/o) + ^i- et = is Xlj ^t/-^ equal to Using the notation introduced above, we infer that the period-1 investment, /i=r($(/o)+ei), increases with in period 1. Iq. This generates more wealth and therefore more investment More investment in period is the familiar wealth effect due to intertemporal consumption smoothing. Since markets are incomplete at i = 0, the initial investment /q satisfies ^'{Io)-p{IoJi) where p{Io,h) the aggregate if = aA 0, = This is is is the risk = Ro, premium on (20) private equity. This relation defines investment Iq as a function of Rq and for but dio/dli investment 7o premium a\f{Io)f'{Io)^*{h) demand premium on risk (19) > > if cr_4 private equity 0. If production risks are We observe that dIo/dI-[ and the demand p(7o, 7i) is a decreasing function of 7i, because the anticipation of low (high) im-estment (low) interest rates in later periods, in When I\. for 7o is = instead We stress that the aA > 0, the risk therefore increasing in 7i. the future leads investors to expect high and current investment expressed by (20) propagation and amplification mechanism. 0), = The optimal Ro- and thus discourages (encourages) risk-taking future = fully insurable (174 zero and condition (20) reduces to $'(/o) is then independent of the future investment The complementarity between ii-^^ it arises only when is cr^ in the present. the heart of our > and that it hinges simply on the property that high risk premia on private equity predict recessions in the near future. The functions C*(VV) and I' {W) = W U C*(W) standard Ramsey model. The interest rate a'(I)= 1/ (l-|-{$'(/)a'(*(7))}'"-^^V The second-order condition It follows that dIo/dRo = is $'(/). are simply the optimcJ consumption and saving rule in the MPC The and then ?'(/) s function a* is determined by the functional equation r-a'(I). of the individual decision problem implies 9[$'(/o) l/(9^G/9/o) < 0; and dio/dh = 15 {ff')/(d^G/dIo) f" • D p(/o, Ii)]/dIo cx^ > 0, since sd ?*' < G/dIo < 0. 0. We now To be 1. When Ro IT we assume that the slump originates specific, endowment = 4 For simphcity, we also treat the ei.^'^ 0, by (20) the optimal investment we conclude that dio/dei fixed, of an anticipated recession or investment slump at date consider the impact at date = 0, an exogenous decrease in date-1 aggregate in and investment On is 0; = dW\/de\ and dl\lde\ 1, the other hand, when a a > 0, h the investment levels 7o and scale reduction in Wi = impact of the and dli/dei > We The effect (19). feedbacks to even lower overall Thus, when markets does not affect in period 1 and the impact of the exogenous wealth shock on contemporaneous income and induces private agents to by the wealth I*'. /o. initial down <&(/o) are complementary by + ^i' The reduction which in turn implies a further reduction in anticipation of the (endogenous) further reduction in h and another round of feedbacks between exogenous shock can be quite large. Indeed, and \\'\ and /o is initiated. dlo/dei > 0, /] The dWi/dei > 1, ay\. conclude that, in the presence of undiversifiable idiosyncratic production is (20). signals high future interest 1 their risky investment in period 0. These impacts are stronger the higher I*'. aggregate shock With in 7i. not amplified. in Iq implies a further /i = slump The anticipation of an exogenous negative wealth shock in period rates as exogenously fixed.-"' independent of the expected decline /q is are complete, the anticipation of a recession or an investment investment in period Rq initial interest rate risks, any given propagated from one period to another via the dynamic complementarity in investment; the contemporaneous impact of the shock shock becomes more persistent, since it is amplified; and the dynamic impact of the takes more time to revert to the steady state. Several remarks are in order about the kind of amphfication and propagation in our model. incomplete markets generate a particular form of pecuniary externality. In the presence of First, uninsurable production decide how much risks, risk taking depends on futiure interest rates. But, when private agents to save and invest in any period, they do not internalize the impact that their choices have on the equilibrium interest rate and therefore on aggregate risk taking and investment in earlier periods. Second, the pecuniary externality generates a kind of dynamic macroeconomic complementarity. 'The case effect ' f = of aggregate productivity shocks is very similar but slightly harder to analyze because of the direct on the marginal product of capital. This is equivalent to assuming an infinitely elastic supply for savings. is derived from the contemporaneous Euler equation. The In our model, the suppb' for savings at anticipation of a recession in period 1 (lower ei) increases the period-0 supply of savings under either complete or incomplete markets, but decreases the period-0 demand for but not to investment under only incomplete markets. The endogeneity of the interest rate thus tends to dampen offset the eimphfication and propagation mechanism we are proposing. The cahbrations of Section show that the mechanism can indeed be quite powerful in general 16 equihbrium. 5 will Because interest rates are endogenous and influence low aggregate risk taking, the anticipation of investment in one period feedbacks into low aggregate investment in earlier periods. Low levels of aggregate investment can thus be self-sustaining for long periods of times. This dynamic macroeco- nomic complementarity the basis of amplification and persistence over the business cycle. is reader must be familiar with a standard example of macroeconomic complementarity - an with production exfernalities, as world, an individual's marginal productivity of capital stock of capital. There is economy Bryant (1983) and Benhabib and Farmer (1994).^^ in is assumed to be increasing thus complementarity in investment, in the The In this aggregate our model. Unlike our model, like in however, production externalities are exogenous and ad hoc. The complementarity in our model is instead endogenously generated by the pecuniary externality we analyzed above; it is a genuine general-equilibrium implication of a market imperfection. Third, this endogenous macroeconomic complementarity hinges on the fact that idiosyncratic uncertainty affects production/investment. (1994) and Krusell and Smith (1998), who thus not present in the economies of Aiyagari It is consider only endowment could not have found the propagation and amplification mechanism We also risks. we want to emphasize the fundamental premises driving our This explains why they identify in this paper. result. First, the willingness to invest in risky production depends on the ability to insure or self-insure against future variations in the return of are obviously such investment. Second, this ability much more is lower during recessions. These two premises general than our specific model. ^* to invest in risky production is lower when a recession is They alone imply that the anticipated to persist in the near future, which can slow down recovery and make the recession partially that our results are robust to We willingness self-fulfiUing. more general frameworks and empirically We are thus confident relevant. ^^ conclude that the presence of undiversifiable idiosyncratic production risks generates a powerful dynamic macroeconomic complementarity. In the presence of aggregate uncertainty, this mechanism can amplify the impact of an adverse aggregate wealth or productivity shock on con- temporaneous output and investment, and can increase the persistence in investment and output over the business cycle. '^Cooper (1999) provides an overview of macroeconomic complementarities. For example, in models with risk averse agents, incomplete insvirance and credit markets imperfections, the anticipation of a higher interest rate for borrowing, a higher probabihty to need credit, or a higher probabihty to face a binding borrowing constraint, will most likely induce the agent to take less risk and thus to invest less, even if his current funds for investment are not constrained. ' The heart in principle of our argument is simply that higher and casual observation suggests it is risk premia on private equity predict recessions. This probably true. 17 is testable Steady State 4.4 We now demonstrate how the presence of capital stock at the steady state. system (14)-(17). Theorem We A undiversifial)le idiosyncratic steady state production risks reduces the a fixed point (Cqo, ^'oa, is I'^oo, ^oo) of the dynamic easily show: The consumption 2 (Steady State) There exists a steady state. ^'^ level Coo is — ^{Kao)-I^oo, while the interest rate and the aggregate capital stock satisfy Roo = $'(/^oo)-Poo, ln(/3i?oo) The first = —al al demand p^ are complete {a a > ~ and/or Ug <^e > = 0); but R^ < + f{K^fa\] (21) (22) . second for productive investment; the We premium on private = note that i?oo 1//? when markets that the risk-free rate is below the discount rate under incomplete markets has been proposed as a possible solution to the low risk-free rate puzzle Weil, 1992; Huggett, 1993; Constantinides The comparative and equity; 1/ p in the presence of undiversifiable idiosyncratic risks The property 0). [ol the risk is the standard deviation of indi\-idual consumption. is {a A = (l-K^f equation corresponds to the aggregate corresponds to the aggregate supply of savings; Oc = m-TC)f{K^)f'{K^)a% Poo and statics of the steady state Duffie, 1996; (e.g., Heaton and Lucas, 1996). can easily be derived from (21)-(22): Proposition 4 (Comparative Statics) The capital stock (Aoo) unambiguously increases with the endowment risk {(Je), the discount factor other hand, the effect of the production risk {(Ja) We will demonstrate in and the mean productivity (/3), is (^4). On the generally ambiguous. Section 5 that, for most reasonable parameter values, K^o is actually decreasing in a a- Proposition 4 and our numerical findings in Section 5 establish that the distinction between endowment and production aA = 0, risks is Consider critical. first the case where ^e as in Aiyagari (1994) and Krusell and Smith (1998). In this case, there on private investment; the marginal product of capital is is no risk > but premium always equal to the interest rate; and the steady state reduces to o '^ = A higher sa\dngs, " endowment ^'/r^ risk implies a higher and thus reduces the interest (l^l/i^^)2 consumption rate. stability. 18 ="^^--2 risk, increases And, since the See the Appendix for a discussion on uniqueness and r ln(/?i?oo) -dJ N ^^''-^ . the precautionary supply of interest rate is equal to the marginal product of capital, the capital stock necessarily increases. This is indeed the finding of Aiyagari (1994). Consider now the case where cr^ > Production 0. premium on risk introduces a risk private investment and breaks the one-to-one correspondence between the stock of capital and the interest aa rate. Indeed, G^). If both the supply of savings affects down agents scale their production even ambiguous. The investment in aj\ raises the risk effect, premium on interest rate. It should then when a a is when the of savings or the is demand high ^. We implausibly low. An increase effect effect typically dominates, implying typically negative. has to dominate. One is when the precautionary interest elasticity of the steady-state supply of savings for investment. is in consumption not very small, not very sensitive to shifts in either the supply is In terms of our model, the latter case corresponds to verify these insights in the numerical simulations of the next Section, which demonstrate that K^o decreases with o^ unless the is unambiguously negative. be no surprise that the investment implying that the steady-state interest rate sufficiently is weak, implying a small response of the supply of savings to increases itself is Another investment (unlike private investment and decreases the capital stock for any given There are two cases where the investment risk. for increases, the savings effect can be small, or on the other hand, that the general-equilibrium impact of a a on K^o motive and the demand (like Ue) Therefore, while Aiyagari (1994) et invests under incomplete insurance, elasticity of intertemporal substitution al. suggested that the economy over- we instead conclude that the most likely case is that of under- investment. Calibration and Numerical Results 5 In this section, income we economy and simulate the impact of uninsurable calibrate our infinite-horizon on the steady state and the speed of convergence to the steady risks state. Calibrated Economies 5.1 We first K" a e , consider technology and risks. (0, 1). For instance, of the mean We when a a = production, replace Oe by Cef{Koo)- We A= next normalize 0.25, the f{K^). We We choose a Cobb-Douglas production function, f{K) which permits a a to be interpreted as a percentage rate. standard deviation of gross output, crAf{Koo), represents 25% \, We accordingly rescale Oe by the steady-state output; that can thus interpret both a a and Ce as percentage next consider preferences. = An important difficulty is, we rates. with exponential preferences is that the degree of relative risk aversion and the elasticity of intertemporal substitution are not invariant; at 19 consumption level C, the former a meaningful calibration, way + and the adjust F and Under complete markets, for to 7 and an of r and ^ <l! = 'i> /C. To remedy this problem and obtain we perturb the parameters in example, the steady-state level of consumption C;,(q,/3, 5).2i every {a, If for such a and intertemporal of risk aversion intertemporal substitution equal to ;/; we (3,8) at the steady state. more complicated similar under incomplete markets, but slightly is rest of the is C^ = calibrate T = C^{a,f3,8), we can then match a degree of relative risk aversion equal tp elasticity of as 'I' = 6-1)/q-(5][q/(/?"^ +6-1)]1/(1'°) j/iC^{a,P,6) and latter is some meaningful measures that the steady state matches substitution. [{P'^ we C T is The calibration for the reasons described in Appendix B. Overall, a calibrated /3 is economy is (/3, 7, V', i, 5,(7^, the discount rate, 7 measures the aggregate degree of relative risk aversion, aggregate elasticity of intertemporal substitution, q ation rate, and a a and endowment 5.2 = parametrized by a vector €"^ (Tg is where measures the ip the income share of capital, 6 (Je), is the depreci- are the standard dexiations of uninsurable idiosyncratic production and risks, respectively, as GDP. percentages of Appendix B (See for further details.) Calibrated Steady State Consider a calibrated economy £^™' = a, tp, 7, (/?, 6, a a, (^e)- We can easily characterize the compar- ative statics of the steady state near complete markets Proposition 5 (Calibrated Steady State) As we move away from complete markets, Roo decreases with either a^ or a a; Koc increases with ip>±, where As we oA is result, it + (/3'^-l) [(/?"^-l) discussed earlier, the demand. As a risk ±= endowment raises the risk premium on force dominates depends 5 provides a lower private equity for R^ and increases First, the risk. [ip), A = if effect of the productivity impact of an increase in a a on for investment. Which technology (a), and markets {a a and 0^). Proposition high Therefore, as long as -'This foUows from C'^ The and therefore reduces the demand i) is *(/Ci,)-i^i, and ^'(K^^) is consistent with implies a high interest elasticity of the supply of xp savings, which in turn implies that the steady-state interest rate consumption A'oo- the elasticity of intertemporal substitution, which our earlier discussion in Section 4.4. in and only be moderated by a decrease in investment. Second, an increase in a a on preferences bound if risk a^ affects precautionary savings but not investment unambiguously reduces may and K^o decreases with a^ il-a)6] l{2a^). fundamentall}- different for two reasons. precautionary savings (Jg; is not very sensitive to variations not too small, the investment effect dominates. = i?;, 20 = 1//3 => X^ = [a/(/r^ + 6-l)]^/''"°\ We ^ note that the lower bound example, is less than 0.20 we consider annual frequency with a narrow if then (.95, .35, .05), ^= and thus of capital, 0.02. Similarly, set suggest an EIS around 1, {(5, = a, 5) if we consider and certainly well above model that Koo may increase with definition for capital, and thus set (/9, = a, 8) a longer time interval and a broader definition ^ = then (.75, .70, .25), For for all plausible values of (/3,q,(5). 0.20, Since most empirical evidence 0.14. seems extremely unlikely in terms of our it ct^. Numerical Simulations of the Steady State 5.3 We have run various simulations and we have identified the following patterns as we vary a^. When V very small (typically is < Kao 0.20), a single-peaked function of a a- is completing the markets increases capital accumulation but may for moderate or high decrease capital accumulation V' > (typically if we globally decreasing function of a a. In this case, Figure 1 illustrates is we start from highly incomplete markets, are too close to complete markets. 0.20), the accumulation. Besides, the impact of Ue if investment more risk In that case, effect On the other hand, always dominates and K^ is a sharing unambiguously increases capital always to reduce Rx and increase Koo- the monotonicities of the capital stock Koo and the net interest rate Too = RBC models in annual frequency. We set = 0.95, 7 = 4, ^ = 1, A) or a — 0.35 (Panel B). Panel A thus corresponds to a broad i?oo~l for a specification typical of — 6 0.05, and a — 0.70 (Panel definition of capital (physical and human capital) and Panel B to a narrow capital only). In each graph, the solid line corresponds to Ce In K^o monotonically decreases as a^ all cases, higher the higher the income share of capital. aA = 100% lower is when a about 25% lower than = varies We = and the dashed one to Ue from to 100% and the drop can not be dramatic. The effect persistent, the abihty to self-insure or adjustment costs. is should be limited, much and stronger and investment is = 0.35 (Panel B), and 40% Hence, the such idiosyncratic shocks are highly if subject to long irreversibilities is if we think of human capital formation, large projects, or other investments that involve specialization, indivisibilities, we can not irreversibilities or effect of With Persistence in idiosyncratic production shocks and long irreversibilities are certainly empirically valid assumptions, especially Unfortunately, Koo that an idiosyncratic production shock lasts only one year. short transitory shocks and infinite lives, agents can easily self-insure. R&D in 50%. 0.70 (Panel A). The above simulations assume risks = observe, in particular, that the capital stock at complete-market value when a its definition (physical explicitly and long horizons. introduce in the model persistent idiosyncratic production risks adjustment costs, for then the model loses its tractabihty.^^ Nonetheless, "'With persistent productivity shocks, an individual's optimal investment becomes a function 21 of his we contempo- can implicitly capture these effects in our simulations, by simply increasing the length of a time We period. then interpret the interval between and the average t and t + as the horizon of an investment project 1 of an idiosyncratic productivity shock. life Figure 2 considers the example of a 5-year investment horizon. As previously, rate over the 5-year period; now 5% and the depreciation rate to be approximately really dramatic. insurance when a = we also set = At a a 'y — 4, i/j = and a € i, 100%, the capital stock 0.35 (Panel B); 15% of it is per year, implying is {0.35, 0.70}. 30% of what it — /3 The we let the discount = 0.75 and 6 K^ on effect of aj^ 0.25 would have been under the complete-markets level when a — is full 0.7 (Panel A). Figures 1 and 2 demonstrate another related markets imply both a low point. In contrast to Aiyagari (1994), incomplete and a low capital stock. risk free rate And, the risk free rate in an incomplete-markets economy can be a largely downward biased proxy of the marginal product of capital. In Panel aA = B of Figure 2, for example, the marginal product of capital 100%, as compared to a risk-free rate of just The simulations duction to is (7e risks. = 0. We also provide a useful insight The dashed when year per year. on the interaction between endowment and pro- and lines in Figures 1 4% 18% per is 2 correspond to o-g = 50% and the solid ones observe that the steady state becomes less sensitive to a^ as a a increases. because when aA self-insure against is large, individuals are already holding a buffer stock that both investment and endowment The risks. This can be used to precautionary effect of a^ similarly diminishes with a^, implying that the investment effect dominates more easily when there is already a lot of precautionary saving in the economy. We that of also observe that the endowment risk the capital stock K^o at impact of production when a^ — on the risk the two types of risk take comparable value. — 50% (^e is dominate capital stock tends to In Figures well below the complete-markets one. That 1 and 2, when is, production and endowment risks make equal contributions to idiosyncratic income variation, the adverse investment effect of production risk tends to dominate the precautionary savings effect of both types of income risk. This finding is suggestive of the fact that the dynamic macroeconomic complementarity we have discussed works as a 'multipher' for the steady-state impact of a^- We conclude that the quantitative impact of a a. on raneous idiosyncratic productivity. This is K^ is ^'' clearly quite large within our model. obviously not important for our qualitative findings, but it complicates aggregation and precludes a closed-form solution of the general equilibrium. -''The numerical results we present in Figures the effect of a a on Roo and strengthens its other hand, 7 tends to have a small ambiguous the risk premium on 1 and impact on 2 are not very sensitive to either Kcx>, because effect, since in'vestment. 22 it i/' or 7. A higher ip raises the interest elasticity of savings. weakens On the a higher 7 increases both the precautionary motive and Unfortunately, we do not know of any ob\aous empirical analogues of a a or We know, (Tg. however, that idiosyncratic production, entrepreneurial, and investment risks appear to be quite substantial the first 34% For example, survival rates of private firms in the United States are only in reality. 10 years of a firm's to entrepreneurial activity is And, even conditional on life. On extremely wide. over survival, the distribution of returns the other hand, private savings are overall very low in the United States. These facts suggest that substantial underinvestment is indeed the most likely scenario. Numerical Results on Persistence 5.4 We argued earlier that the presence of uninsurable production dynamic macroeco- risks generate a nomic complementarity, which can be the source of amplification and propagation over the business We now cycle. illustrate this effect by examining the effect of ct 4 on the speed of convergence to the steady state. In Appendix C, we economy S"^'' = (/?, ip, and approximate the linearize the 7, a, 5, local dynamic system (14)-(18) around the steady state of a calibrated a a, de). We dynamics by \og{Kt+\l K^o) 1-A. Incomplete insurance slows down convergence Numerical simulations show that such Consider our earlier example of a with (3 = ^ — 1, and a 6 0.75 (discount rate w 5% •^'* as 5- year — we then effects to the steady state rate is 1-A decreases with a^- if plot the convergence rate and the half-life of an to 100%. Clearly, the convergence rate decreases to 100%. = We calibrate the model « 5% per year), 7 = 4, 2). 0.25 (depreciation rate definition of capital (a both physical and human capital (a These are substantial ^^og{Kt/ K^). The convergence investment project (Figure per year), 6 almost doubles as a a increases from — the case for a wide range of plausible parameter values. we vary a^ from With a narrow rapidly with ca- aflfects is {0.35, 0.70}. In Figure 3 aggregate wealth shock, calculate the stable eigenvalue A of the linearized system The 0.7, = 0.35, effect is Panel B), the even stronger half-life of a shock when incompleteness Panel A). on the convergence rate, which suggest that imdiversifiable pro- ductivity risks can play a useful role in generating endogenous persistence over the business cycle standard in RBC models with aggregate uncertainty. depend on idiosyncratic risks affecting 'The hajf-life T of a deviation from the steady state is we discussed before. ^^ defined by A''^ = 1/2; that Figure 3 demonstrates the asymmetry between production and endowment risk again that these results production and investment choices, thereby introducing the kind of dynamic macroeconomic complementarity ' We finally stress once risk. is, why our That is T= logj A. On D persis- the one hand, endowment does not introduce the kind of dynamic macroeconomic complementarity that production risk does. On the other hand, the precautionary motive tends to boost up savings below the steady state and thus to speed up convergence. 23 tence findings could not have been identified by Krusell and Smith (1998). Concluding Remarks 6 This paper examined a standard neoclassical growth economy with heterogeneous agents, decen- and uninsurable production and endowment tralized production, specification for preferences the aggregate dynamics. and We risks, we obtained Under a CARA-normal risks. closed- form solutions for individual choices found that uninsurable production shocks introduce a on private equity and reduce the aggregate demand As a for investment. risk and premium result, the steady-state capital stock tends to be lower under incomplete markets, despite the low risk-free rate induced by the precautionary motive. Undiversifiable idiosvTicratic production risks also generate a powerful dynamic macroeconomic complementarity between future and current investment. Originating a pecuniary externality, this mechanism output and investment, slows of the business cycle. amplifies the impact of down convergence The complementarity in an exogenous aggregate shock on to the steady state, and increases the persistence rehes critically on the fact that uninsurable risks affect private returns to production. This explains the contrast between this paper and earlier research on economies with endowment shocks (Aiyagari, 1994; Krusell and Smith, 1998). The model tion.^^ rules out We expect that wealth effects should strengthen our results in instance, investment rates and stringent poor and any wealth effects on risk-taking because of the chosen demand would be weak during CAFL\ specifica- more general frameworks. For a recession not only because high borrowing credit conditions are expected in the near future, but also because agents are less willing to engage More in risky projects. generally, the CARA-normal specification appears to play no essential role in our argument that undiversifiable production risks introduce a negative feedback firom future borrowing rates and credit conditions to current investment. Credit-market imperfections and non-convexities in production have been viewed by many au- thors as a souixe of persistence in the business cycle. Although these departures from the neoclassical growth model are not considered here, we to generate underinvestment find that incomplete risk sharing alone Therefore, while the convergence rate tends to decrease with a a, dynamic macroeconomic complementarity appears " when Krusell not miss when a^i to and a^ are equal, the convergence rate abstracting from them. We it is Introducing borrow- tends to increase with dominate the convergence and Smith (1998) have argued that wealth much by sufficient and introduce a powerful propagation mechanism. The presence of uninsurable production risks reduces the individual's willingness to invest. instance, is effect of ffe. Furthermore, the precautionary savings. For lower than under complete markets. effects are quantitatively small. This may suggest that we do expect, however, that wealth effects will be quantitatively significant crecht constraints are accompanied by idiosyncratic technological shocks. 24 ing constraints would in addition restrict the ability to undertake risky projects, which should make investment more sensitive to future credit conditions. We thus expect that credit constraints would only reinforce both the steady-state and the business-cycle Moreover, our findings stress that it is effects documented in the paper. not only contemporaneous credit conditions that matter for investment, but also anticipated future credit conditions. A detailed quantitative assessment of our RBC dard mechanism wo\ild require the calibration economy with decentralized production, borrowing and both aggregate and idiosyncratic productivity shocks. framework of and this of a stan- constraints, isoelastic preferences, This can be done by combining the paper with the numerical analysis of Krusell and Smith (1998). Wealth effects financial constraints are then likely to reinforce our quantitative findings. and Krusell and Smith (1998), we Finally, like Aiyagari (1994) as exogenous to the model. There in private information,^^ while markets a long tradition in models where incomplete markets originate is some more recent contributions study economies where incomplete Although beyond the scope of this paper, it is work to production economies with idiosyncratic production risk risk sharing originates in the lack of important to extend this also treated incomplete line of commitment. and endogenous incomplete markets. "'See for example Townsend (1982), Green (1987), Banerjee and Newman (1991), Atkeson Cole and Kocherlakota (2001). See Kehoe and Levine (1993), Kocherlakota (1996), and Alvarez and Jermann (2000). 25 and Lucas (1992), and Appendix A: Proofs Proof of Proposition We (Individual Choice) 1 A more have already presented the main steps the main text. below, maintaining the assumption that there is no premium on risk detailed derivation follows treatment of the individual's decision problem, under arbitrary prices, and Calvet premium, it is w.l.o.g to follows that Tr^j it max assets U{cl) + We 1. > 0,\/m 1. In the absence thus rewrite the Bellman equation (6) as Tflf+i f3U E;tw V.i We min t+\ Var((u'j_|_j) (23) successively soh'e for the optimal portfolio of risk\' and the optimal consumption-investment choices. (c'^ , wealth, Vart(w/+i) k^ 6^ , = f) , the optimal portfolio (0^ j)^_j minimizes the conditional v^ariance of Var^ [yl^+i/(fc^+i) ^L.t = -Coi-t + 4+i + E/=i 4t+i^'J The FOCs dm,t+i on the asset span. This yields A(^j = + i^^i+i ^^^ deterministic constants and orthogonal to the span of ; + >lt+i/(fc^+i) kJ^j t;^ The optimal rff+i- imply • This result has a natural geometric interpretation. i<^t = assume that Efd^.j+i — 0,Vm > sugge.sts a two-step solution Given any ej_,_j presented in Angeletos is the portfolio problem reduces to a simple mean-variance problem. Since the asset (8), structure includes a riskless bond, The above general (2000). Following of a risk A financial assets. For d^+i + all we can t. and jy^^j t+i^^t+i ^^^ Vm > ef+i project (regress) = ej_j.j random 1. ^^^j \-ariables, di+i + /l(_,_j ^l+i' and where ^j+i-measurable and portfolio hedges fully the diversifiable component of idiosyncratic risks i&inX=i = The and Ug = (A + vUi)f{K+i) + — Vart(ej^.j) (l-'5)fc/+i Var,«,)^a2 + /(fc^^^)2a2,. We now turn to the optimal d /(^-f+i)-f+i+e(+1 residuals represent the undiversifiable risks. Var(77j^j), Var(£^^.j). + 4+1 + ^if We let By EstAj^-^ = A. E(ej_,_j (24), wealth after Thus, Etwi^, = (24) t+i- = 0. a\ = Var((/7j_^j) hedging reduces to Af{f4^,) + (l-<5)fc^+i + wj_^_-^ + optimal We define $(fc) = E^w^+j = $(A;/+i) + 9{t consumption, savings, and investment decision. {l-6)k and G{k,rd) j. (c^, /cj_^j, 0Q = = 6^^ and = $(fc)-^ [al + f{k)^a\] .It follows that Combining with (23), we conclude that Efty^_^i-raj_^jVar((wj^i)/2 = G{kf_^_^,Ta'^^y) +9^ Af{k) and - the J maximizes [/(c^) + 0U {y/+i [G(fc^+i, Fa^+j) 26 + e^o J} , (25) subject to c^ + + /cj_,_j — 6q^/ Rt w\. The FOCs with respect to k^ and ^qj give dG }s^+i^(fc^+i,ra^+i), (Without loss of generality, we assume = dG/dk, above two yields Rt that Next, the envelope condition reduces to = a^Wf + h^-^ \na[. We infer FOC with respect to ^qj as = Qt+i' that a\ — a^ and bl — U'{c{). Using (3) and (7), this = 6(-* Ino^. Using (3) and (7), we = pRtU'[v^^, [E,<i^ra^'+jVari«j)/2] U'{4) a(_|_j dVi{vj{)ldvj U'[Vf{wl)] is ^+i~^ ~ ^^^t+i ^f ^^'-^ } al^, = ^^^ consumption rule, the above reduces to = mtU' U'(4) Combining the condition (12). is, c^ rewrite the Using interior solutions throughout our analysis.) [Et4+,-TYait{4+,)/2 . This gives the Euler condition (13). consumption rule and the budget constraint imply that d^+i/dwf Finally, the Plugging this relation yields (11). in the Euler condition, we infer that a^ = l/[l + {al^-^Rt)~^]. — aj^ji?j(l-aj). Iterating forward QED Proof of Proposition 2 (Savings) = Since Var(«;) 0. Let f{k) miplies k o\ > = a'i+a\f{kf,dVaT{w)/dal > =~A' I {2R 2i?/f. = ^/k and, w.l.o.g., 6 + Pct^)". but 5Var(«;)/af7^ Then, G{k,f) 1. Hence, Var(u;) = al = = f{k)^+[2a^^fik)f'{k)][dk/da\] R= {2Vky'^iA~falVk] and dG{k,f)/dk + o\A^ l[2R + Va\)~ and dV&i{w)lda\ < -^ QED Proof of Proposition 3 (Investment) By /xF and dk/dT —-^o\, where d'^G/dk'^ < and thus ^ > 0. dependence of ^ on F and a\. proportional to (11), R= the implicit function theorem, the first-order condition, ~cr'^- dft/dRs > (The for all s ji t. f{k)f'{k)/{-d'^G/dk'^). With some but not We first is > = The second-order serious loss of generality, then conclude that dk/da'^ exact when F ~ QED 27 dG/dk, implies dk/do\ =- is condition implies we can ignore the proportional to and the second when ct^ ~ -F and dk/dT 0.) Finally, is from Proof of Theorem Existence Here, is (General Equilibrium) 1 proved Angeletos and Calvet (2000), by talcing the limit of finite-horizon economies. in we only characterize the general equilibrium. at, ^t,j. Given this, (12) implies A,-^ Finally, (18) get (15). Assumption G j J, —f^ l^e and using the and and = — at a^ — (13) reduces to + }{Kt + ,)o% fact that E E.c^+1 = eJ ^ E <:-) E kUr^t ^ we all (11) implies a^ (12) then reduces to (14) A"(, Vi, j. = * ln(/3i?0 + ¥.tc>t+i~< Aggregating the above across = we note that First, E ^n ) = = Wtf+i--'^(+i Kt+x — Ct. ^t+i, from aggregating the budget constraints and using (17) follow QED 4 (no aggregate uncertainty). Proof of Theorem 2 (Steady State) The steady Since aoo > 0, or equivalently state we ^ K= K^o < and K. [o-2,cr2 The second condition defined by the system (21)-(22). also have Roo bounded between m2[0, A') is > Since Roo > 1, the first {F')^^{8/A). Therefore, R^ is We 1- find + f{Kfo\), it equation implies AF'{Koo) bounded between useful to consider the functions mi(l, ^'^] defined by mi(i?) = (0, — > + > 1, A'oo is 1-^ and [0, l//?- +oo) and m2{K) = We observe that mi is decreasing in R and m2 is increasing in K For any K G [0, K), mi{R) = Tn2{K) has unique solution, Ri{K) = mj^[m2(A')], which maps [0, +oo) onto (l,mj^((Tg/2)] maps 1//3 (2*/r)(l-i?-i)-2ln[l/(i?^)] and al + f{K)^a\. the equation and 1 < implies R^o . C the (1,/?"^]. Similarly, A] onto [l,-|-oo). equation (21) imphcitly defines a function /?2(A) that first This function is decreasing, due to the second-order condition of the individual's problem. Consider the function and R2iK) — > -|-oc', implying the functions Rj and The above proves and also multiplicity A(A) = R2 A(A) existence. stability. cycles, or -*-oo. We and A ^ 0. we observe that Ri(K) also note that The system We (21)-(22) earUer discussed If this A(A) = indeterminacy and the /?i( A)-l > may local bounded The graphs of dynamics allow us to analyze is strong enough, multiple steady states, In Angeletos and Calvet (2000), arise. cr_4 and ae- When instead (jyi stability of the incomplete-markets steady state follow, uniqueness and stability of the complete-markets steady state. In this paper, . 0. is how incomplete markets introduce an dynamic complementarity such complex dynamics arise only for very large zero, uniqueness When therefore intersect at least once and there exists at least one steady state. macroeconomic complementarity. endogenous /?i(A)-7?2(A'). 28 we show and Ug are that close to by continuity, from we consider only the where a 4 and a^ are not plausible case steady state in Section 5 is This also ensures that our calibration of the too large. QED meaningful. Proof of Proposition 5 (CompEirative Statics) We used the functions 7?i and R2 define in the proof of Theorem We of the steady state with respect to the economy's parameters. which when the steady-state 2 to analyze the monotonicity > consider the case \R'2{Koo)\ An increase in a^ or /? pushes down the function Ri{K) and leaves the function R2{K) unchanged. The steady state is |i?j(/Coo)|, is necessarily satisfied is unique. therefore characterized by a lower interest rate and a higher capital stock. Similarly, an increeise in 1-6 and A pushes up R2{K), also leading to a lower interest rate and a higher capital stock. increase in F or a^ pushes down both R\{K) and R2{K), Ta^ reflecting the fact that An enters in both the demand for investment and the supply of savings. F and a a can therefore have ambiguous QED effects, as verified in simulations. Proof of Proposition 6 (Calibrated Steady State) — Consider a calibrated economy 8'^ the output- capital ratio at date The state. q* = {l3~^-\ calibration of + i5)/a. A= F and implying f'{Koo) ^ = ere)- = (l-^) + and u [(i?oo-l)/i?oo][goo/(goo-i5)] A= {1-P)q* /{q*-6). u standard Ramsey model. in Rx) and (7A2)/(i/'i/) dqao/d{cr^^) goo are rf(cr^) > When ^ 2, ct'^ = R^ ^ and (T^ A obtained by keeping and dq^o = 2{q* -6) / {qoo-6) = R* 1/P, and f{Kt)/Kt = Kf~^ denote Cod K^o — ('?oo^<5) at the steady FCoo — 7 and '^/Koo — i'i<l*-6), and thus dKoo/daA < if F and 1/ In Angeletos 8"^ q^o Appendix we describe the calibration _^. = (26) and Calvet (2001) we When ct^ = o-g = = q* ^ (/3"^-l + 6)/a, . constant in (26). and only Hip > and characteristics of our exponential-utilities . are positive but close to 7Agoo(l-:^/^)f^(cr^), where 3^ Appendix B: Calibrating In this = \n{moo)^-^{o\ + ol). agoo(l^Aa2^), prove that a steady state exists for any calibrated economy markets), qt Q^co and Appendix C) implies (see Let The steady-state system (21)-(22) thus reduces to i?oc where f, {P,'y,ip,a,8,aA, 0. (complete hke in the the first-order variations We thus get d(lni?oo) {q*-6)(fr^-l)/{2a). It =- foUows that QED * of F and $ that permit us economy utiUties economy. 29 to map the preference to the preference characteristics of an isoelastic- We consider F. first consumption of aggregate economy S so that FCoo risk aversion at the We We observe that the degree of relative risk aversion at the steady-state level = 'I'. We pick some constant 7 and The parameter 7 thus corresponds 7- aggregate next consider We TCoo- is level, to a constant measiu'e of relative which permits a meaningful calibration of the model. observe that the elasticity of intertemporal substitution (EIS) at the ^ /Coo- steady-state level of aggregate consumption is we could S such that ^/Coo = problematic C) is some constant V and pick restrict the following reason. for = l-2{l + The above The convergence /?+;^/?2(i-Q)(/ri+5-l) + A/ a function of is rate g depends as well on '^/K^ and and 17,4 a A, there is 1 This calibration, however, + P+^(3\l-a){(r^+d~l) is Appendix direct effect of 174 we have discussed on the convergence rate g captures in Section 4. ^ I Koo g. to vary with a a- Instead, we want CARA-normal We But, since through the dependence of g on also an indirect effect -4/? markets are incomplete, the convergence caHbrate £ so that 'f/Coo remains invariant at some prespecified our ^- for risk aversion, rate under complete markets (see When {a, 0,8). The Oe- the macroeconomic complementarity on what we did In analogy to given by g of incomplete-markets restrict the level, '^ K^ jK^. is If and specification) is we were to then we would be permitting would thus be compounding the direct and the indirect to control for the indirect effect (which a function effect of an unfortunate implication of partial out the direct effect (which captures the macroeconomic complementarity introduced by uninsurable idiosyncratic production control for the indirect effect, we must keep meaningful parametrization of 'i/Koo- where q* to equal suggests = '^ / Koo constant We observe (/3"^-l-t-(5)/a. Therefore, restricting at the how invariant at xp{q*-6). We pick The parameter tp we vary a a- This dynamic risk). To in turn requires a — that under complete markets Coo/Koo {q*-6), the elasticity of intertemporal substitution, 'I'/Coo, complete-markets steady state implies to calibrate *. as aa some constant '^ I ip K^ = ijjCac/Kx = and restrict 4'{q*-8)- 8 so that '^ The latter /K^c remains thus measures the elasticity of intertemporal substitution around the complete-markets steady state and our caUbration permits a meaningful assessment of the impact of market incompleteness on the convergence rate.^^ We think that the cahbration of 'I' we propose above the incomplete-markets steady state so that "P/Coo rate is = tp is the most reasonable one. The alternative of cahbrating yields similar results in the following sense: a decreasing function of cr^ and an increasing function of ^/Kao- Because K^ the overall effect of a a on g turns out to be non-monotonic in some simulations. However, if we look between the incomplete-markets convergence rate and the shadow complete-markets convergence latter is defined as the convergence rate of a complete-markets economy that has the same 30 The convergence typically decreases with 'i a a, at the difference rate, where the /Koo as the incomplete- we chose a Cobb-Douglas Finally, as discussed in Section 5, rescale 17,4 and a^ as percentages of output. Definition (Calibrated Economies) A We ^/Koo = Appendix We first vector zt Lemma [0, ^P{q*-6), q* = (r'-l calibrated + and thus define: sponds to an incomplete-markets economy 8 7, specification for the technology S)/a, economy £™' = = (/3,7, ^, a, {j3,T,'^, F,6, A,a'j^, a'^) F{K,L) - iC^L^-", A = (5, ct^, Ce) corre- = such that FCoo 1, a\ = oa, and Dynamics Around the Steady State C: Local observe that equilibrium paths can be calculated by a backward recursion of the state = {at,Ct,Wt). (Equilibrium Recursion) For any = state vector 2f+i +00), there exists a generically unique {at, Ct, {ot+i, C't+i, W^t+i) Wt, Kt+i,Rt) € {0,1) x R^ x G (0, 1] R^ x i? x satisfying the equilibrium recursion (14)-(17). Proof. Given zj+i we = (a^+i, Ct+i, H^t+i) for solve equation (14), = namely Rt some t, and with Lj dG{Kt+\,Tat+\) / dK, = for IVi, we proceed as follows. First, Kt+\ as a function of {Rt,at+\). This equation might assume multiple solutions. However, generically, only one of them corresponds maximum of the individuals problem. Second, we substitute Kt+i from the above into namely Wj+i = ^{Kt+i, 1), to obtain an equation in {Rt, at+\, Wt+i). We solve this equation to a global (18), for Rt as a function of Kf+i as a function and Wt. We (aj+i, Wt+i)- We = then plug this back into Rt dG{Kt+i,Tat+i)/dK, to get of {ot+i, Wt+i). Finally, equations (16)-(17) then assign unique values to at, Ct, QED then let H denote the equilibrium recursion markets economy, then + mapping; zt = H(zt-)-i) is implicitly defined at =\l[l Ct =Q+i-*ln(^/?i)-Fa2^J/(X,+a)24+a2]/2, Wt =Ct+Kt+i, this difference is by {at+xRt)-\ always negative and increasing indeed to slow down convergence. 31 in cr^. That is, the 'true" impact of oa is where Rt = dG{Kt+-iSat + i)/dK and = A',+i '(li'f+i). <I> _daj_ ac, D.H of H is da, Q 9a, + ] The Jacobian ac. 1 awt+i .ML We observe that dKt+i/dWt+-i dRt = l/^'{Kt+i) > 0. and -Vf{Kt+i)f'{Kt+i)o\ < dat+i Let x{y) dRt 1 dWt+i ^'(Kt+i) ^ {f"{Kt+i) [A-rat+if{Kt+i)<jl] -at+i[f'{Kt+ifral} < 1/(1 + y~'^) v/{l + v) and note that x'(^) ~ + 1/(1 = ^0^ 0. [x(''-')/^]^- Since at = x{at+\Rt), we infer that dRt dat at dat+i at+iRt Rt-at^ dat+i dRt dot at+i dWt+i \at+iRt Future propensity Ut+i has an ambiguous direct effect (due to the on current propensity effect a^. There is both a positive complementarity of future and current consumption) and a negative indirect effect (the precautionary motive causes a decHne ^\n{PRt)-ra^+^ [f{Kt+i)^a^^ + aj] /2, we the current interest rate Rt). Since Ct in Tat+iifiKt+iYa'^ Rt dat+i Rt 91V', +1 dCt dRt dWt+: = Ct+i- infer that dRt dCt dat+i An <0. d\\' (+1 2 la* + 1".4 + ai] f{Kt+,)f'{Kt+i) >i>'iK,+i) increase in at+i and W't+i leads to a decline in the current interest rate, which has a positive effect on current consumption. On the other hand, the increase in Oj+j and Wt+i implies that the agent bears more risk between time t and time f + 1. Let I denote the identity matrix. The characteristic polynomial, P{x) = det(D2H-a;I), can be rewritten as P(x) = dat d{Ct da t+i The roots of P + Kt+i] OK,f+i 1 dWt + dWt + i 1 + X dCt dat dat+i dWt+i' are the eigenvalues of the backward dynamical system. (The eigenvalue A considered in Section 5 thus satisfies P{l/X) — and 1/A > 32 1.) Since P(-oo) = +oo and P{+oo) =-oo, There always < \K2{Roo)\ When Thus when \K[{Roo)\ an eigenvalue in (1, there = markets are complete, a = ~ {<yA,'^e) dCt 0, dat +1 (7 Obviously, x = =x2-x|l + We to an unstable manifold. has one root in the interval two eigenvalues in (0, 1) and one root (0, 1) We note that, We 1. has 1. + in (1, > 0. (T=0 dKt +1 dWt +1 (7=0 contained in the interval and Q{1) < (0, 1) 0. We and thus corresponds infer the quadratic +00). Overall, the Jacobian matrix The 1. D^H Q has stable manifold under can explicitly calculate the root that corresponds to when markets dKt+i D^H if (/3-x) (3(x), where and one eigenvalue larger than complete markets has thus dimension > dW,t+i (7=0 next observe that (5(0) the interval the stable manifold. is = Kt+,) dW,f+i the one eigenvalue. This j3 \s + d{Ct at least is dCt and = characteristic polynomial thus reduces to P{x)\^_q Q{x) and only we know that 0, /?, dat +1 (7=0 if a unic}ue steady state, the Jacobian matrix is +00), and the dimension of the stable manifold dat The Simple calculation shows that P(l) > exists a real eigenvalue. are complete, R^ = $'(Koo) ~ 1//3 and 1_ (3, dWt+i (7 = dRt dWt+, (7=0 dCt dWt+, The polynomial Q{x) (7 production function (1-q)(/?"^ + 5-1)/ K^. eigenvalue is Finally, (7e A = ^ { 1 ^Al3'f"{K^)>0. dWt+, (7=0 therefore reduces to Q{x) If the Rn = is = x2- [1 + f3-^i>P^Af"{K^.)] X Cobb-Douglas, f{K) = K'^, then + p. A/"(Xoo) = (a-l)Af'{K^)/K^ =- Therefore, with complete markets and a Cobb-Douglas technology, the stable 1/x and + p+-j^pHl-a){p-'+6-l)+ J when markets 1 + P+-^p^{l-a){p-'+6-l are incomplete, the stable manifold is -4/3 one- dimensional as long as a a and are not very large. (Locally, this follows from our finding that the cubic P{x) has only one root outside (0, 1) when (ja — <7e = and by continuity 33 of the P{x) in a a and a a- More generally, we check numerically that this convergence rate a A and a,, per convergence is se. the case for a function of Since P{x) We omit rate. is is 'i// I\r^,. our simulations in Section like 5.) The incomplete-markets the complete-markets one, but a cubic, there is it is it is too long and not interesting. For our 5, we use Mathematica to solve analytically it for the particular and then evaluate also of function of a closed-form solution for the incomplete-markets the formula, however, because numerical simulations in Section rate in general all for the convergence "Was Prometheus Unbound by Chance? Risk, Diver- numerical \-alues. References [1 Acemoglu, D., and sification, Aghion, Zilibotti, F. (1997). and Growth." Journal of Political Economy 105. 709-751. Banerjee, A., and Piketty, T. (1999), "Dualism and Macroeconomic Activity," P., Quarterly Journal of Economics 114, 1359-1397. Aiyagari, nal of S. R. (1994), "Uninsured Idios\Ticratic Risk and Aggregate Saving," Quarterly Jour- Economics 109, 659-684. Aiyagari, S. R. (1995), "Optimal Capital Income Taxation with Incomplete Markets and Bor- rowing Constraints," Journal of Political Economy 103, 1158-75. Alvarez, F., and Jermann, U. J. (2000), "Efficiency, Equihbrium and Asset Pricing with Risk of Default," Econometrica 68, 775-798. Angeletos, G.M. (2002), "Optimal Capital Income Taxation with Idiosyncratic Production Risks and Incomplete Markets," MIT mimeo. Angeletos, G. M., and Calvet, L. E. (2000), "Incomplete Markets, Growth, and the Business Cycle," MIT Working Paper #00-33. (Available Atkeson, A., and R. E. Lucas, Jr. (1992), "On at the SSRN website www.ssrn.com.) Efficient Distribution with Private Information," Review of Economic Studies 53, 427-453. [9 Banerjee, A., and Newman, Review of Economic Studies A. (1991), "Risk Bearing and the Theory of Income Distribution," 58, 211-235. 34 [10] Banerjee, A., and Newman, A. (1993), "Occupational Choice and the Process of Development," Journal of Political Economy 101, 274-298. [11] Benhabib, J., and Farmer, R. (1994), "Indeterminacy and Increasing Returns," Journal of Economic Theory [12] 63, 19-41. Bernanke, B., and Gertler, M. (1989), "Agency Costs, Net Worth, and Business Fluctuations," American Economic Review [13] Bernanke, B., and Gertler, M. (1990), "Financial Fragility and Economic Performance", Quarterly Journal of [14] 79, 14-31. Bryant, Economics (1983), J. 105, 87-114. "A Simple Rational Expectation Keynes-Type Model," Quarterly Journal of Economics 97, 525-529. [15] Caballero, R. (1990), "Consumption Puzzles and Precautionary Sa\-ing," Journal of Monetary Economics [16] 25, 113-136. Calvet, L. E. (2001), "Incomplete Markets and Volatility," Journal of Economic Theory 98, 295-338. [17] Castaneda, A., Diaz-Gimenez, J., and Rios-Rull, V. tion Business Cycle Dynamics," Journal of [18] Monetary Economics Income Distribu- 42. Cole, H., and Kocherlakota, N. R. (2001), "Efficient Allocations with Hidden Storage," Review of Economic Studies [19] (1998), "Exploring the Hidden Income and 68, 523-542. Constantinides, G., and Duffie, D. (1996), "Asset Pricing with Heterogeneous Consumers," Journal of Political Economy 104, 219-240. [20] Cooper, R. (1999), Coordination Games Complementarities and Macroeconomics, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge [21] Galor, 0., and Zeira, J. (1993), "Income Distribution and Macroeconomics," Review of Eco- nomic Studies [22] University Press. 60, 35-52. Green, E. (1987), "Lending and the smoothing of uninsurable income," in E. Prescott and N. Wallace, eds., Contractual Arrangements for Intertemporal Trade, Minneapolis, Minn.: University of Minnesota Press, 3-25. 35 [23] Heaton, and Lucas, D. J., J. (1996), "Evaluating the Effects of Incomplete Markets on Risk Sharing and Asset Pricing," Journal of Political Economy 104, 443-487. [24] Heaton, and Lucas, D. J., J. (2000), "Portfolio Choice and Asset Prices The Importance of Entrepreneurial Risk," Journal of Finance 105, 1163-1198. [25] Huggett, M. (1993), "The Risk Free Rate in Heterogeneous Agent, Incomplete-Insurance Economies," Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control [26] Huggett, M. (1997), "The One-Sector Growth Model With Idiosyncratic Shocks," Journal of Monetary Economics [27] 17, 953-969. Kehoe, T., 39, 385-403. and Levine, D. (1993), "Debt-Constrained Asset Markets," Review of Economic Studies 60, 868-888. [28] Kimball, M. S. (1990), "Precautionary Saving in the Small and in the Large," Econometrica 58, 53-73. [29] Kiyotaki, N., and Moore, J. (1997), "Crecht Cycles," Journal of Political Economy 105, 211- 248. [30] Kocherlakota, N. R. (1996), "Implications of Efficient Risk Sharing without Commitment," Review of Economic Studies 63, 595-609. [31] Krusell, P., and Smith, A. (1998), "Income and Wealth Heterogeneity in the Macroeconomy," Journal of Political Economy 106, 867-896. [32] Leland, H. (1968), "Saving and Uncertainty The Precautionary Demand for Saving," Quarterly Journal of Economics 82, 465-473. [33] Ljungcjvist, L., MIT [34] and Sargent, T. J. (2000), Recursive Macroeconomic Theory, Cambridge, Mass.: Press. Marcet, A., Obiols-Hom, F., and Weil, P. (2000), "Incomplete Markets, Labor Supply and Capital Accumulation," Universitat Pompeu-Fabra Working Paper. [35] Moskowitz, T., and Vissing-Jorgensen, A. (2001), "The Private Equity Puzzle," American Economic Review, forthcoming. [36] Piketty, T. (1997), "The Dynamics of Wealth Distribution and the Interest Rate with Credit Rationing," Review of Economic Studies 64, 173-189. 36 [37j Quadrini, V. (2000), "Entrepreneurship, Sa\ang and Social Mobility", Review of Economic Dynamics, [38] 3. Rios-Rull, V. (1995), "Models with heterogenous agents," in Cooley, T. F., ed., Frontiers of Business Cycle Research, Princeton, [39] New Jersey: Princeton University Press. Ri'os-RuU, V. (1996), "Life-Cycle Economies and Aggregate Fluctuations," Review of Econom.ic Stvdies 63. [40] Sandmo, A. (1970), "The Effect of Uncertainty on Saving Decisions," Review of Economic Stvdies 37, 353-360. [41] Townsend, R. M. (1982), "Optimal Multiperiod Contracts and the Gain from Enduring Relationships [42] Under Private Information," Journal of Political Economy 90, 1166-1186. Weil, P. (1992), "Equilibrium Asset Prices in Economies with Undiversifiable Labor Income Risk," Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 37 16, 769-790. Figure l.A (a = 0.70) Interest Rate Capital Slock and MPK % par icar Keo MPK 7 6.5 6 5.5 5 4.5 Oa 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.2 O.i 0.4 0.6 0.8 Figure l.B (a = 0.35) Interest Rate Capital Stock K> 6.75 % pi and MPK yeer —— — " 6.5 / ---i^^ 6.25 6 >« ^^-^^/ ^^.^-^^ ^ \X ^ 5 \ 5.25 0.6 _ — "T!"::!————..,..^ _= — " 0.2 0.8 of intertemporal substitution is 1. Panel B. The solid lines correspond to o^ = = 50% (of steady-state GDP). The 100% of steady-state GDP. ~i]^^^^^^ The income share of capital 0.6 0.4 is of one year. The discount 4, and the and 35% in and the dashed ones to Oj risk aversion 70% (no idiosyncratic endowfment risk) 0.£ in Panel is A show the steady-state level of the capital stock, the interest rate, (MPK), as idiosyncratic production risk Oa varies between zero and plots and the marginal product of capital ^"~-«i,i.,,,__^ 4.5 FIGURE 1. We perform an RBC calibration of the model with a time period rate is 5% per year, the depreciation rate is 5% per year, the degree of relative elasticity / 5.5 XX 5.5 0.4 ^^y^ 6 \\ \ 5.75 0.2 yy 6.5 ^^^*N^^ MPK Figure 2.A (a =0.70) Capital Stock Interest K^o % per Rate aiid MPK ^yBer 17.5 2.5 MPK 15 2 12.5 1.5 10 7.5 1 5 0.5 2.5 Oa 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.2 0.8 0.4 0.6 0.8 Figure 2.B (a =0.35) Capital Stock Interest K„ 0.5 % per ^ ^ -. ' 0.4 Rate and MPK year: MPK 17.5 ^-<:- 15 12.5 ^^"<;^ ^^^^ 0.3 0.2 10 7.5 5 0.1 2.5 Oa 0.2 FIGURE 2. We 0.4 0.6 0.2 0.8 assume the same parameter values as in Figure 1, but 0.4 now 0.6 0.8 use a five year time period and the duration of an idiosyncratic production shock). The solid lines correspond to Oe = and the dashed ones to Oe = 50%. The plots show the steady-state level of the capital stock, the interest rate, and the marginal product of capital tMPK), as idiosyncratic production risk Oa varies between zero and 100%. (for both the length of an investment project Figure 3.A (a =0.70) Half Life of a Shock Convergence Rate years 40 35 30 y / 25 20 Oa 0.2 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0.4 0.8 0.6 Figure 3.B (a =0.35) Half Life of a Shock Convergence Rate % per year 14 7 / 6 / 10 5 y / 4 Ot. 0.2 FIGURE 3. 0.4 Assuming the 0.6 same parameters of the deviation from the steady The solid lines correspond to a^ 0.2 0. as in Figure 2, we 0.6 0.8 plot the convergence rate and the half-life state as idiosyncratic production risk = 0.4 and the dashed ones to o^ = 50%. Oa varies between zero and 100%. Date Due 3/1^/^ Lib-26-67 MIT LIBRARIES 3 9080 02246 0965 ilMliMiliMiMll :;j:L^!;::a;i::iJijui'ai;l:i:iiiJ^l'llfitIia;jiiOilii:ii:LiJjiil!lJ>in!iLi;a